Chapter 8.
8.1 The
Fifteenth Century Crisis
The starting point of our
investigation is the second half of the fifteenth century, because only from
this date on we have access to reasonably detailed sources on the agrarian
history of
The first, or Kievan, cycle began
with the East-Slavonic colonization of territories that eventually became
What was the scale of the
catastrophe? How do we interprete the words of the chronicler, “few people
remain in all Russian lands”? According to the archaeological evidence, the
finds of leather shoe remnants and birch scrolls in Novgorod cultural layers
declined by a factor of two during the first half of the fifteenth century (Izyumova 1959, Konovalov 1966). The implication is that the population declined by a
similar factor. As we saw in earlier chapters, dealing with the economic
effects of the Black Death, one of the indicators of a demographic catastrophe
is a sharp decline of grain prices and growth of real wages. After “the Great
Pestilence” in the Northwest prices halved, and labor became very expensive.
The daily wage increased to approximately
According to archaeological data,
one fifth of villages in the Moscow region were deserted (Yushko 1991:52-53). Population losses were undoubtedly even more severe,
because the surviving villages must have also lost population to famines and
epidemics. The rate at which stone buildings were constructed in Moscow and
Tver declined abruptly by factor of 2.5–3 (Miller 1989). As happened after the Mongol conquest, several chronicles
were terminated, creating a gap in the chronicle coverage of Russian history
extending to the mid-fifteenth century (Lurie 1994).
The socio-political crisis in the
Moscow region was severe and lasted half a century—from the devastating Tatar
invasion led by Yedigei in 1408 and the first plague epidemic of 1418 to the
end of the internecine war in 1453. The cause of the crisis was the financial
collapse of the
With the Great Prince in captivity, the
civil war flared up anew. The Tatar raiding parties crossed the
8.2 Expansion
(1460–1530)
The crisis of the fifteenth century
resulted in a significant decline of population numbers. As a result, during
the second half of the century Muscovite
As we noted above, real wages were
very high during the period following the end of troubles (the daily wage was
more than
As to the land rents, we know that the
typical size of land worked by peasants in central
Table 8.1.
Estimated peasant budget (
Assumptions |
Local units |
Standard units |
Total area
cultivated |
15 desyatins |
|
Planted
with rye |
5 desyatins |
|
Seed
input, rye |
40 puds |
|
Yield
ratio, rye |
1:3.3 |
1:3.3 |
Net
harvest, rye |
92 puds |
|
Planted
with oats |
5 desyatins |
|
Seed
input, oats |
55 puds |
|
Yield
ratio, oats |
1:3.1 |
1:3.1 |
Net
harvest, oats |
115.5 puds |
|
Net
harvest, rye + oats |
208 puds |
|
Household
size |
8 persons |
8 persons |
Per capita
net yield |
26 puds |
|
As
calculations in Table 1 show, the estimated per capita consumption for a
typical household of 8 persons, cultivating 15 desyatins, was
The reign of the Great Prince Ivan
III (1462–1505) “was the most tranquil and happiest time” in the Muscovite land
(Soloviev 1989:III:169). Famine, pestilence, and Tatar attacks abated for a time.
Government documents of this period contain multiple mentions of new lands
brought under plough and the resulting growth of cultivated area (Cherepnin 1960:166). Ivan III conducted two censuses in the Novgorod Land, one
during the 1480s and another c.1500. During the period between the censuses the
population increased by 14 percent. Thus, population growth rate was on the
order of 1 percent per year (AHNWR 1971:48-50). No comparable data exist for the central region, but
fragmentary evidence suggests that the number of peasant households in various
administrative regions (volosti) or
manors (imeniya) increased by a
factor of 1.5, 2, or even 3. Integrating these and other data, A. I. Kopanev (1959) concluded that the population of Russia grew by 50 percent
during the first half of the sixteenth century, and reached the level of 9–10
mln.
The most densely populated regions
were located in Northwestern Russia around
8.3
Stagflation (1530-1565)
Population and Economy
Chester Dunning (1997, 1998, 2001) was the first to use the demographic-structural theory in
the analysis of Russian history during the sixteenth century. He noted that
population growth beyond the means of subsistence in Russia during the
sixteenth century led to price inflation (in this following the conclusions of earlier studies, see
Blum 1956, Mironov 1985).
Before 1530 the price of grain
remained relatively stable, with rye costing around 10 dengas per quarter (
Tracing the connection between
overpopulation and inflation, however, is complicated by an uneven regional
development. Thus, the earliest signs of stagflation appeared in the Northwest
well before the central region around
In the most populated regions, thus,
stagflation began already in the early sixteenth century, and this process was
speeded up by the high levels of extraction by the state and the gentry. At the
same time, there was significant variation even within the Northwest. The
conditions in Bezhetskaya and Shelonskaya Districts were more benign than in
the Derevskaya and Vodskaya Districts. The first two districts increased in
population between 1500 and
Documentary sources are much sparser
in the central regions, but here too population growth led to the diminution of
peasant land allotments. By the middle of the sixteenth century there were
instances where two or even three peasant households were sharing the standard
allotment of 15 desyatins (Kolycheva 1987:64). At this time an average household in the Borisovskaya
District, near Vladimir, had 7.5 desyatins, less than in the Derevskaya District
(Kolycheva 1987:64). In the Belozerskiy District there was only 6 desyatins per
peasant household, which was insufficient to produce enough grain to last until
the next harvest (Prokop'eva 1967:102).
Overpopulation lead to chronic
peasant indebtedness. Peasants borrowed from the monasteries (the chief
moneylending institution in
In mid-sixteenth century, after a
long hiatus, famines and epidemics reappeared in
The first signs of the impending
crisis, thus, are observable well before the start of the Livonian War
(1557–82) that is often blamed by historians for the economic decline of the
Population growth in the central
regions drove the real wages down. In
Monastery records provide us with
information about real wages for workers hired year-around. The pay of
agricultural laborers consisted of an in-kind portion, which equaled 16 puds or
Another indicator of overpopulation
and rural underemployment is the flowering of crafts, increase of trade, and
growing urbanization. Peasants of the densely populated Derevskaya and Vodskaya
districts of the
Elite dynamics
The top level of the Russian social
hierarchy was occupied by the appanage princes who were close relatives of the
The second level of the hierarchy
was occupied by “service princes,” who included many descendants of the great
princes who ruled the
The third level consisted of the
“Old Muscovite” boyars, such as Morozovs, Zahar’ins, and Chelyadins. The
ancestors of these boyars were the closest henchmen of the
The princes and boyars together
comprised the magnate stratum of Muscovite
Table
8.2. Some numerical data indicating elite
dynamics (from various sources)
Period |
|
Total |
Source |
1520s |
20,000 |
South
Frontier army |
(Herberstein 1988:113) |
1560s |
100-120,000 |
Total
Muscovite army |
(Skrynnikov 1988) |
1580s |
65,000 |
S.
Frontier army |
(Fletcher 2003:77-78) |
1580s |
80,000 |
Total
Muscovite army |
(Fletcher 2003:77-78) |
1630 |
15,000 |
South
Frontier army |
(Chernov 1954:125) |
1630 |
27,000 |
All
servitors |
(Chernov 1954:125) |
1651 |
39,000 |
All
servitors |
(Chernov 1954:125) |
1700 |
23,000 |
Gentry,
owning peasants |
(Vodarski 1977:49, 64,73) |
1737 |
46,000 |
Gentry,
owning peasants |
(Vodarski 1977) |
During the first half of the
sixteenth century the
Table 8.3.
Percent of gentry servitors in the Novgorod Land with estates (a) less than 150
desyatins, (b) between 150 and 300 desyatins, and (c)more than 300 desyatins in
1500 and 1540.
year |
<150 des. |
150-300 |
>300 des. |
1500 |
22 |
30 |
48 |
1540 |
39 |
39 |
22 |
Sociopolitical instability
We can follow the dynamics of
socio-political instability in central
Figure
8.1. Time distribution of coin hoards
found in the
The course of the narrative history
is largely in agreement with the coin hoard dynamics. The reigns of Ivan III
(1462–1505) and Basil III (1505–33) were characterized by internal unity and
successful territorial expansion. When Basil III died in 1533, his son Ivan IV
was only three years old. During Ivan IV’s minority the state affairs were
first directed by his mother, Helen Glinsky, and after her death in 1538 by the
boyar duma (the supreme council of the state). The period of boyar rule
(1538–47) was wracked by a continuous strife between two noble clans, the Shuiskys
and the Belskys. The power changed hands several times and imprisonments,
exiles, executions, and murders proliferated (Riazanovsky 2000:145).
The boyars divided among themselves
provincial governorships and sharply increased their demands (kormlenie) on the population (Soloviev 1989:III:436, 440). The magnates interefered in the process of distributing the
service estates to the gentry. There is documentary evidence that the princes
and the boyars seized large tracts of this land as their own (Kobrin 1980:172). The gentry felt themselves squeezed by large landowners,
the lay magnates and the monasteries. Litigation for land between the servitors
and monasteries became common during the 1540s (Zimin 1960:76, 81).
Another useful indication of
intraelite competition and fractionation is provided by the dynamics of “precedence”
litigation. Precedence (mestnichestvo)
was a system of appointments for state positions, based on a hierarchical
ranking of boyar families and prior service. Precedence litigations were
disputes among the military leaders over service assignments (Kollmann 1999). Before 1540 the were only between three and five litigation
cases per decade, but during the 1540s it jumped to 30 (in the Kollmann
database, see the solid curve in Figure 8.2). Another huge jump, to over 200,
occurred during the 1580s. Thus, the intensity of precedence litigation seems
to provide a good leading indicator of intraelite struggles to come.
Figure
8.2. Precedence litigation in
The failure of crops in 1546 lead to
a famine next winter. When a great fire swept
Growth of taxation
The “good” half of Ivan IV’s reign
also saw prolonged and intense external warfare. On the eastern front,
These wars were extremely expensive
and resulted in a sharp increase of the state’s press on peasants (Figure 8.3).
As we noted above, peasant consumption in parts of
Figure
8.3. Dynamics of state taxes in Bezhetskaya
District (in kg of grain per household) (Nefedov 2003).
8.4 Crisis
(1565–1615)
In 1565 Ivan IV created a separate
institution, called the oprichnina
(from oprich—apart, or beside), that
divided the state, the elites, and the whole society right down the middle (Riazanovsky 2000:150). Ivan established a separate administrative structures for
the oprichnina and the rest of the country, zemschina,
which continued to be governed by the boyar duma. There were two sets of
officials, one for the oprichnina and another for the zemschina. Countryside
was also divided into two parts, and many landlords in the oprichnina territory
were transferred out, while their lands were given to the new servitors of the
tsar, called the oprichniki.
Skrynnikov (1996) determined that more than 150 magnates, almost all of them
of the princely status, were removed to the Kazan region.
In the beginning there were one
thousand oprichniki, but eventually their numbers grew to six thousand. Urged
on by Ivan IV the oprichniki instituted a reign of terror against the boyars,
their relatives and associates. A number of towns, the best known of which is
In essense, oprichnina was a coup d’état from above, in which Ivan IV
used one segment of the elites (and elite aspirants) to wage civil war against
the rest. Once the oprichniki played
their role, they were in turn repressed. In 1572 Ivan declared the oprichnina
abolished.
It was during this period of intense
external and internal conflict (the Livonian War and Oprichnina) when
Famine, plague, and intraelite
conflicts weakened the ability of the state to repel external invasions. In
1571 the Crimean Khan Devlet-Girey gathered together a huge host and invaded
We can assess the scale of the
catastrophe of the 1570s by turning to the best documented region, the
Northwest (Nefedov 2003). In Derevskaya District one-third of peasant alottments (obezhi) was deserted due to mortality
resulting from famine and plague. Other alottments were abandoned by peasants
unable to fulfil their tax obligations. In Derevskaya District three-fifths of
alottments were deserted, although it is unknown what proportion was due to
mortality, and what to emigration. Parts of
Bezhetskaya District lost 40 percent of population to famine and disease.
Some idea of what happened in the central region, can be gained from the
conditions on the estates belonging to Troitse-Sergiev and Iosifo-Volokolamsky
monasteries. Around
As usual, the population decline
brought in its wake some amelioration of the economic conditions for the
commoners. Thus, daily wage increased sharply during the 1570s. The
Another sign of decreased population
pressure was the fall of land rents (Nefedov 2003). The quitrent (obrok)
on the gentry estates fell by a factor of three, from 10–12 to 3–4 puds puds
per “soul”. On the state-owned land the rents were approximately halved.
Corvée obligations also declined by a factor fo 2 or 3 (Nefedov 2003).
Thus, the demographic catastrophe of
the 1570s led not to increased levels of peasant exploitation, as some
historians have claimed, but, on the contrary, a significant lightening of the burden.
But this also meant that the ability of the state and the elites to extract
resources from peasants, using economic methods, declined in a major way. In
real terms, taxes paid by each household shrank 3-, 4-, or even 5-fold, as in
the Shelonskaya District around
The gentry servitors were also hard
hit. Many estates completely lacked peasants to work the land. Only 7 percent
of land was cultivated in the Moscow District (uezd), and 25 percent in the Kolomna District. In the Derevskaya
District more than a third of servitors had no peasants (AHNWR 1971:II:71, Kolycheva 1987:184). Lacking resources to support themselves the gentry
abandoned their estates. The Muscovite army, the bulk of which consisted of the
mounted gentry servitors, lost half of its numbers (Schtaden 1925:99, Skrynnikov 1988:13).
Ivan IV died in 1584. The reign of
his son Fedor (1584–98) was a relatively peaceful period, even though Fedor was
feeble-minded and the government was again in the hands of the boyars. This
interlude between the periods of high political instability, the oprichnina (1565–72)
and the Time of Troubles (1604–13) was probably due to the exhaustion of
potential warring factions, rather than any lasting solution of the basic
contradiction between elite overproduction and declining commoner population.
The root cause of the continuing
instability, which eventually led to the state collapse and civil war, known in
the Russian history as the Time of Troubles, was the acute shortage of labor,
economic distress of the elites, and the financial crisis of the state. The
situation was similar to that of
However, enserfment could not
resolve the economic problems of the elites. During the reign of Fedor
(1584–98) the Russian army consisted of 80,000 cavalrymen, who received annual
pay (in addition to service estates). Every year 65,000 cavalrymen served on
the southern frontier guarding against the Tatar raids. Not all of these
warriors were gentry, but, on the other hand, not all gentry received salary.
Thus, by the end of the sixteenth century there were at least three times as
many gentry servitors, compared to the regin of Basil III (1505–33), when
20,000 cavalrymen served on the steppe frontier. It is reasonable to assume
that the overall numbers of the gentry increased by the same factor (three or
more), whereas the commoner population was roughly the same as under Basil III
due to the demographic catastrophe of the 1570s. In other words, the social
pyramid became extremely top-heavy towards the end of the sixteenth century. It
is clear that Russian peasants could not support such great numbers of the
gentry, even if they were deprived of all the agricultural surplus that they
produced. This contradiction could be solved only by abating the elite
overproduction, which is what happened in the first half of the seventeenth
century.
Enserfment was not a discrete event;
rather it was a process that occurred in stages spread out over many decades. A
key period in the evolution of serfdom was the end of the reign of Fedor
(1584–98) and the reign of Boris Godunov (1598–1605), when the government,
under the pressure from the gentry, issued a number of legislative acts that
restricted the movement of peasants and extended the period during which a
fugitive serf could be forcibly returned to his master.
Enserfment gave the landowners more
power to extract surplus from the peasants. This is, for example, what happened
at Iosifo-Voloklamsky Monastery, where the first attempt to increase
corvée by 50 percent met with peasant resistance, and had to be
rescinded (Koretskii 1970:283-4, Peasant_History 1990:257). Subsequent landlord initiatives were supported by the
central authority. In 1601-3 corvée was doubled in many monasteries by
the tzar’s edicts.
Because of fragmentary data, no
quantitative statements can be made about the conditions of peasants on the
servitor estates. However, we know that petty gentry had very few peasants. For
example, the average servitor in the Tula region was supported by only four
peasant households (Koretskii 1975:86), but he had to equip himself for military service every
year. As a result, the majority of servitors were compelled to deprive the
peasants of all their surplus, leaving them nothing to build up stores in case
of recurrent crop failure.
The Time of Troubles
The socioeconomic situation in the
first decade of the seventeenth century was in certain respect similar to that of
forty years earlier, although during the 1560s it was the tax press of the
state, not the elites, that pushed the peasants to the brink of survival. The
trigger again was a very poor harvest resulting from cold and wet weather in
1601. Grain prices started climbing almost immediately. In the spring of
The great famine of 1601–3 had far
reaching effects on the population, the state, and the elites. First, it
resulted in vast suffering and an enormous mortality shock delivered to the
general population. Avraamii Palitsin reported that 127,000 people were buried
in Moscow alone (Palitsin 1955). Another witness wrote that “one third of the Muscovite
Tsardom has perished from the famine” (Koretskii 1975:131). Starving peasants attacked the houses of wealthier peasants
and servitor manors. Starting in the Fall of 1602 banditry outbreaks became
endemic in many regions (Koretskii 1975:208).
Second, it brought about the collapse
of the state finances. The government of Boris Godunov took extraordinary
efforts to alleviate the suffering of the common people (Dunning 2004:69–70). It attempted to control the prices, but without success.
The Tsar then used the state’s grain reserves, selling the stored surplus at
half the market’s price and distributing loaves of bread to the poor free of
charge. Finally, the government was forced to spend huge amounts of money by
giving away coins and bread to the poor in
Third, the famine created a huge
pool of disaffected and desperate counter-elites. Petty gentry were hit by the
famine as badly as peasants. Many of them were forced to sell themselves into
slavery in order to survive. In 1602 slave sales were nine times greater than
in normal years (Dunning 2004:69). The trained cavalrymen, who sold themselves into slavery,
were not employed in agricultural or domestic chores; instead, they joined the
armed retinues of the magnates as elite military slaves. As the famine
lenghtened, the lords found themselves unable to support their large retinues,
and many cut the military slaves adrift. These individuals were desperate,
“armed and dangerous,” and there were very many of them. According to a
contemporary estimate twenty thousand former elite military slaves migrated to
the southern steppe frontier, where they joined the ranks of disaffected
cossacks and frontier servitors (Dunning 2004:72).
Unemployed military slaves,
destitute servitors, runaway serfs, and cossacks from the southern frontier
consituted a huge pool of manpower for the subsequent rebellions and civil
wars. The first outbreak, the so-called “Khlopko rebellion” was little more
than a large band of bandits that operated in the
The next uprising (in 1604) was more
serious and ultimately successful in toppling the state. It was led by an
impostor who claimed to be Prince Dmitrii, the son of Ivan IV. False Dmitrii
had started his invasion of Russia with the backing of the Polish magnates, but
it is probable that the plot was initiated and secretly supported by certain
boyar factions (Bussov 1961:100). The pretender has drawn most of his army from the southern
frontier region where a large numbers of frontier cossacks and servitors were
recently joined by massive influxes of former military slaves, destitute
servitors, and runaway serfs. In April 1605 Tsar Boris suddenly died and the
magnate coalition, which he had until then managed to hold together, fell
apart. Large segments of the elites went over to False Dmitrii, and he entered
We do not need to describe the events of the
ensuing civil war in detail. Suffice it to say that Dmitrii was overthrown and
murdered by a faction of the boyars led by Vassili Shuisky in 1606. Shuisky
became the Tsar, but was deposed in 1610. Meanwhile a series of pretenders
arose one after another, including another Prince Dmitrii who claimed to have
miraculously escaped the death at the hands of the boyars. There was another
popular rebellion led by Ivan Bolotnikov, and foreign interventions by the
Poles and Swedes (at one point the Russian crown was offered to Wladyslaw, son
of the king of
The famine ended earlier: 1604 was a
good year for the crops. The demographic catastrophe had its usual positive
effect on the real wages. Servant wages in monasteries increased by 50 percent
compared to the pre-famine years (Nikolsky 1910). Rye cost 32 dengas per quarter, which was close to the
pre-famine level.
Thus, the years of famine and civil
war resulted in another population decline, although its magnitude was probably
not as great as that of the 1560s and 1570s. Shrinking population led to labor
shortages and increased real wages. However, while after the first catastrophe
the real wages increased by a factor of 2.5, after the Time of Troubles the
increase was on the order of 1.5. The situation of the peasants became better,
and the process of enserfment was de facto rolled back. While all the laws tying
peasants to land continued to exist, in practice they were unenforceable. It
was very difficult to locate and bring back the runaway peasants. This was a
task beyond the resources of most gentry, and no government agencies existed to
give them help. Furthermore, once the situation stabilized the government did
everything to avoid further agitation among the peasants (Shapiro 1965:67). On the southern frontier, peasants were given a legal right
to leave the estates of the gentry (Tihonov 1966:302).
The long and intense civil war
shrank the elite numbers. If during the 1580s the numbers of cavalrymen who
served every year on the southern frontier was 65,000, in 1630 only 15,000 of
elite servitors were able to report for the frontier duty (Table 8.2).
8.5 Conclusion
The end of
the internecine warfare c.1450 created favorable conditions for sustained
population growth. The second half of the fifteenth century was characterized
by abundant land, relatively high consumption levels by the peasants, low grain
prices, high real wages, and low levels of craft development and urbanization.
Internal peace and order prevailed, while externally the state was invovled in
a series of successful wars of expansion.
The first
signs of stagflation become visible in the
Intraelite
competition and fragmentation increased in the middle of the sixteenth century.
The increase in the social tensions is manifested in the government’s attempts
at social reforms and in decreasing sociopolitical stability—e.g., the
The severe
population decline resulted, as usual, in better standards of life for the
commoners. However, the numbers of elites remained very high. Better wages and
lower rents, combined with the smaller producing population, lead to a drastic
decrease of the elite incomes. The elite landed servitors were the mainstay of
the Russian army but at this point the majority of them were unable to equip
themsleves and serve on the frontier. The governemnt was thus forced to bind
the peasants to land in order to give the servitors better ability to increase
the rents. Enserfment resulted in a significant increase in the level of
resource extraction from the peasants, especially by petty servitors who had
only a few peasants to support themselves.
The
sociopolitical instability of the 1560s and 1570s was followed by a relatively
peaceful interlude of the 1580s and 1590s. During this period population
probably increased, but it was still far below the pre-crisis level. Thus, the
basic contradiction between too many elite servitors and too few peasants was
unresolved. The press of the landlords on the peasants resulted in the latter
existing precariously on the verge of starvation, lacking any reserves in case
of a poor harvest. The crop failure of 1601 triggered another massive famine.
During the following three years, general population experienced massive
mortality, the state depleted the treasury while unsuccessfully trying to
ameliorate the effects of the famine, and huge numbers of trained and equipped
military personnel were left without any means of subsistence. The result was a
bloody and prolonged civil war, known as the Time of Troubles.
This
internal struggle resulted in a reduction of elite numbers, but the social
equilibrium was not entirely attained. The second demographic catastrophe
resulted in another population drop and an increase in the quality of life for
the peasants, while the elite incomes again declined. Thus, the economic
position of the elites after the Time of Troubles remained difficult.